Referring Elsevier/RELX to the Competition and Markets Authority
Today, along with Stuart Lawson and Jon Tennant, I have submitted the
below as a complaint to the Competition and Markets Authority, making
good on the advice of Ann McKechin, MP at the BIS Inquiry into Open
Access in 2013. The document is also [available as a
PDF](/images/CMA-RELX.pdf). Re: RELX Group in Industry
58.14/1 Dear Sir/Madam, We write to complain about what we
believe to be the anti-competitive practices of RELX Group in industry
58.14/1 ("Publishing of learned journals") on the following grounds: *
Abuse of a dominant market position * Problems in a market sector The
grounds on which we believe these statements to be true (and on which we
believe any "reasonable person" under English law would reach the same
conclusions) are set out below with reference to 1.) the secondary
academic literature that has studied the scholarly publishing landscape;
2.) previous competition inquiries; and 3.) financial statements from
RELX Group. Further, we write following the advice of Ann McKechin,
previously MP for Glasgow North, who recommended, in a BIS sub-committee
inquiry hearing in 2013, that RELX Group (at that time known as Reed
Elsevier) be referred to the competition commission if it continued to
use non-disclosure agreements. She called this a "profoundly
anti-competitive practice" and said that if this was happening with
public funds "there should be a referral to the Office of Fair Trading"
(HC 1086-i, 2013). ##Background UK Higher Education is funded through a
variety of public and private streams. While much revenue is derived
from student tuition fees as an apparently private source,
quality-related research funding from government is also awarded to
almost every institution through the Higher Education Funding Council
for England (HEFCE). Furthermore, most tuition-fee income is
underwritten by a government guarantee on the loan (the "RAB charge"),
making the majority of "private" revenue also contingent on public
funds. Part of the purchasing from UK universities, funded from this
pool of public money, is devoted to buying subscription access to
learned journals and books in order to further research progress. In the
case of access to Elsevier's portfolio (Elsevier is the trading name of
RELX Group's academic journal division), a national negotiating team was
convened by Jisc, the UK's digital infrastructure body for higher
education, and has been consulting over the last 18 months. The results
of the negotiations that took place with Elsevier are currently being
considered by UK universities. However, the details of the agreement are
under a non-disclosure agreement. In our view, this represents a serious
breach of competitive market practices since it is impossible for other
parties to benefit from price competition. Furthermore, that this is
used in the expenditure of public or publicly-underwritten funds goes,
to the best of our knowledge, against HM Treasury principles for the
commissioning and expenditure of public funds. We believe that this is a
result of Elsevier's abuse of a dominant market position and more
systemic problems of competition in the field of scholarly publishing.
As above, a sitting MP recommended that were this to be continued, RELX
Group should be referred for anti-competitive practices. ##Abuse of a
Dominant Market Position Elsevier is the single largest publisher of
scholarly and scientific articles. The UK university community spends
around £40m per year on access to the ScienceDirect platform run by the
publisher, the Scientific, Technical and Medical division of which made
a £760m adjusted operating profit on £2070m revenue in 2015 (Earney,
2016; RELX Group, 2015, p. 9). Although it is difficult to provide
precise figures due to the disaggregation of the market, as previous
investigations have also noted (see OFT 396, 2002), we believe that
Elsevier exhibits market dominance by the criteria of the CMA by meeting
the following criteria: 1. Elsevier's dominance in this space is
indicated in a range of positions that we believe exceed or come close
to 40% of total supply. A 2002 OFT report noted that the group had a "a
forty one per cent share of the supply of science and technology
journals" (OFT, OFT396, 2002, p. 6). 2. Another realistic and reasonable
estimate in our view is that a grouping of Taylor & Francis,
Wiley-Blackwell and Elsevier account for over 50% of all published
science papers in 2013 and 71% for all psychology papers (Larivière,
Haustein, and Mongeon, 2015). 3. We believe that Elsevier is not
affected by normal competitive restraints. The goods it sells are unique
and non-comparable. If a researcher requires a specific article, then no
substitute good can be found, which works against competitive market
price pressure (Eve, 2014, p. 14). It is our view that Elsevier unfairly
exploits the above dominant market position to avoid price competition
in several ways: 1. We believe that Elsevier uses non-disclosure
agreements extensively in order to ensure that its prices are unaffected
by competition. David Tempest, Director of Access Relations at Elsevier,
for example, argued that were other libraries/institutions of higher
education worldwide to know the amount Elsevier charges for access,
"everybody would drive down, down and down" on prices, leading to users
paying less for accessing these materials (the goal of market
competition). This is captured on video (Taylor, 2013). This represents,
in our view, a substantial discrimination between customers based on
little to no material difference in the circumstances of supply, as a
result of a dominant market position and a desire to avoid price
competition. We see this as consequently unfair to its customers who do
not see the benefits of price competition. 2. Because it holds such a
dominant market position, we believe that Elsevier knows that
institutions of higher education (its primary customers) will suffer if
they do not subscribe to its packages. Because it controls such a large
portion of scholarly and scientific materials (as above) it is able to
leverage an operating profit margin of approximately above 40% in the
STM division since 2011 (Larivière, Haustein, and Mongeon, 2015, figure
7), demonstrating, in our view, substantial market dysfunction. We
believe that this leads to a situation in which it is difficult for
competitors to emerge based solely on Elsevier's dominance. Because
library budgets are finite, but Elsevier controls so much of the supply
chain, we feel that smaller publishers are unable to compete due to the
threat of Elsevier withdrawing its supply to the same customer base.
##Problems in a Market Sector The market space of 58.14/1 is deeply
problematic in our opinion for the following reasons: 1. As above, in
our view a small number of publishers, and especially Elsevier, dominate
the majority of the landscape. 2. We also believe that there is a
problem of a lack of price sensitivity among customers. This is fuelled
by non-disclosure agreements but also the fact that researchers are
encouraged to publish in "respected" journals for hiring and promotion
panels, thereby giving the content to organizations such as Elsevier for
free (often with no remuneration from organizations such as Elsevier),
with little awareness of the strains that this places on institutional
library budgets. 3. Because goods are non-substitutable (a journal
article cannot be substituted for another since each is unique and
novel), little to no downwards price pressure is exerted, which we
believe has contributed to a 300% rise in journal prices above inflation
since 1986 (see Eve, p. 13). 4. Elsevier also control data and analytics
services that are used by universities to assess the reputation of
journals, researchers, and institutions. These services for both
citation metrics (used to evaluate researchers) and for university
rankings are in part based on Elsevier's own journals, so it is our
belief that institutions feel that to be competitive they must have
access to the journals that are used to assess their research quality.
5. We think that further evidence of market dysfunction can be seen in
Elsevier's extreme levels of profit: up to 42% (RELX Group, 2015), more
than double those commonly found in the oil industry (approximately
16%), and far outstripping pharmaceutical companies (around 6.5%). 6.
This problem was noted in a House of Commons Select Committee Inquiry in
2013 (as above) and an MP recommended referral to the competition
authority were such practices to continue. We believe that these
practices are continuing, and indeed worsening, and we would urge the
immediate investigation and intervention in this deeply anti-competitive
and unregulated space (HC 1086-i, 2013). Yours sincerely, Professor
Martin Paul Eve
Birkbeck, University of London (but writing in a personal capacity)
##Co-signed Dr. Jonathan Tennant, Imperial College London (but writing
in a personal capacity)
Stuart Lawson, Birkbeck, University of London (but writing in a personal
capacity) # Bibliography * Earney, Liam, 'Jisc Collections and Elsevier
Agreement: Questions and Answers', Jisc, 2016 [accessed 3 December 2016]
* Eve, Martin Paul, Open Access and the Humanities: Contexts,
Controversies and the Future (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press,
2014) * 'Evidence to House of Commons Select Committee Inquiry', in
Inquiry into Open Access. Fifth Report of Session 2013-2014., by House
of Commons Business, Innovation and Skills Committee (London: House of
Commons, 2013), pp. Ev20-Ev27, Ev68-Ev69. HC 1086-i. * Larivière V,
Haustein S, Mongeon P (2015) The Oligopoly of Academic Publishers in the
Digital Era. PLoS ONE 10(6): e0127502. * Office of Fair Trading, 'The
Market for Scientific, Technical and Medical Journals: A Statement by
the Office of Fair Trading (OFT 396)', Interlending & Document
Supply, 31 (2003), 61–64 * RELX Group, 'Annual Reports and Financial
Statements 2015', 2015 [accessed 3 December 2016] * Taylor, Mike (2013)
Elsevier's David Tempest explains subscription-contract confidentiality
clauses. Youtube.
Referring Elsevier/RELX to the Competition and Markets Authority was originally published by Martin Paul Eve at Martin Paul Eve on December 03, 2016.
Additional details
Description
Today, along with Stuart Lawson and Jon Tennant, I have submitted the below as a complaint to the Competition and Markets Authority, making good on the advice of Ann McKechin, MP at the BIS Inquiry into Open Access in 2013.
Identifiers
- UUID
- 12fb8437-4a58-4cf3-987d-925bc2b0b542
- GUID
- https://doi.org/10.59348/h6y7v-4st03
- URL
- https://eve.gd/2016/12/03/referring-elsevierrelx-to-the-competition-and-markets-authority
Dates
- Issued
-
2016-12-03T16:55:58
- Updated
-
2016-12-03T16:55:58
Citations
- Eve, M. P. (2016, December 3). Referring Elsevier/RELX to the Competition and Markets Authority. Martin Paul Eve. https://doi.org/10.59348/h6y7v-4st03
- Wainwright, J., & (Guille) Bervejillo, G. (2021). Leveraging monopoly power up the value chain: Academic publishing in an era of surveillance capitalism. Geoforum, 118, 210–212. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geoforum.2020.04.012